Legal Sidebar
The FTC’s Proposed Non-Compete Rule
January 23, 2023
On January 5, 2023, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC)
proposed a rule that would ban non-compete
clauses in employment contracts. The proposal relies on the FTC’s putative authority to issue rules
defining “unfair methods of competition” (UMC) under
Sections 5 and 6(g) of the Federal Trade
Commission Act (FTC Act).
A final rule banning non-compete clauses would implicate unsettled legal questions. As a threshold
matter, it i
s unclear whether the FTC has the authority to issue substantive UMC rules. While there i
s case
law holding that the FTC possesses such authority
, analysts hav
e debated whether courts would reach the
same conclusion if presented with that issue today. In addition, even if the FTC has UMC rulemaking
power, a non-compete ban may raise questions about
the scope of that authority.
This Legal Sidebar provides an overview of the FTC’s non-compete proposal and these questions
involving the agency’s legal authority.
The Proposed Rule
The FTC’s proposed rule
would prohibit employers from entering into non-compete clauses with
workers, maintaining existing non-compete clauses, or representing to workers that they are subject to a
non-compete clause. Non-compete clause
s would be defined as any contractual term that prevents a
worker from obtaining employment with a person, or operating a business, after the conclusion of the
worker’s employment with the employer.
While non-compete clauses would generally not includ
e other restrictive employment covenants, such as
non-disclosure agreements and non-solicitation agreements, the proposed rule would treat these
restrictions a
s functional non-compete clauses if they are so broad in scope that they effectively prevent
workers from obtaining employment or operating a business.
Workers protected by the rul
e would include anyone who works for an employer, paid or unpaid,
including independent contractors, interns, and executives. The proposed rul
e would apply to all persons
or entities that hire or contract with workers
, except for entities like banks, common carriers, and
nonprofits that are exempt from the FTC’s jurisdiction. The proposed rul
e would exempt, however,
non-compete clauses between the buyer and seller of a business when the seller who is party to the clause
had at least a 25% ownership interest in the business.
Congressional Research Service
https://crsreports.congress.gov
LSB10905
CRS Legal Sidebar
Prepared for Members and
Committees of Congress
Congressional Research Service
2
The proposed rul
e would preempt any state laws conflicting with it. The FTC
explained, however, that the
proposal would establish a “regulatory floor, not a ceiling,” thus allowing states to provide even greater
protections to workers.
The FTC asserts the proposed rule is warranted based
on research showing that non-compete clauses
negatively affect competition in labor markets by suppressing labor mobility, resulting in lower wages for
both workers subject to non-compete clauses (about one in five American workers according t
o FTC
estimates) and those not subject to non-compete clauses. The FTC also relies on evidence showing that
non-compete clauses reduce competition i
n product and service markets by, among other things, limiting
former workers from
creating new businesses and inhibiting workers from bringing
innovative ideas to
new companies.
The FTC
acknowledged evidence that non-compete clauses lead employers to increase employee training
and other forms of investment, and that these investments are the
“primary justification” for non-compete
clauses. Nevertheless, the FTC concluded that employers have
less restrictive alternatives to protect their
investments, such as
trade secret law, non-disclosure agreements, or using
fixed employment contracts to
prevent workers from leaving shortly after receiving valuable training.
The FTC
grounded its legal authority for the proposed rule in Sections 5 and 6(g) of the FTC Act.
Section 5 prohibits “unfair methods of competition” (UMC), whil
e Section 6(g) authorizes the
Commission to “make rules and regulations for the purpose of carrying out the provisions of” the FTC
Act.
The FTC’s preliminary findings supporting the proposal differed for senior executives and workers who
are not senior executives. The agency preliminarily
concluded that non-compete clauses represent a UMC
as applied to workers who are not senior executives for three independent reasons. First, the Commission
concluded that such clauses are “restrictive conduct that negatively affects competitive conditions.”
Second, it determined that such clauses are “exploitative and coercive” at the time of contracting. Third, it
concluded that such clauses are “exploitative and coercive” at the time of a worker’s potential departure
from an employer. In contrast, the FTC
preliminarily determined that non-compete clauses binding senior
executives represent a UMC based only on the first reason—that is, because such clauses represent
“restrictive conduct that negatively affects competitive conditions.”
As part of the rulemaking, the FTC
sought comment on alternatives to the proposed rule. Specifically, the
Commission asked for comments on whether it should (1) adopt a rebuttable presumption of unlawfulness
rather than a categorical ban on non-compete clauses, and (2) create different standards for different
categories of workers rather than a uniform rule for all workers.
As for the first alternative, the FTC
recognized that a rebuttable presumption could have some advantages
over a categorical ban in that it would accommodate particular situations where a non-compete clause
does not raise competitive concerns. On the other hand, the Commission expressed concern that a
rebuttable presumption would provide less certainty than a categorical ba
n and could lead to confusion
among workers and employers as to whether a particular clause is forbidden.
As for the second alternative, the FTC
observed that state laws addressing non-compete clauses generally
create different standards or exemptions based on workers’ job functions or income. Still, the FTC
preliminarily
concluded that a uniform rule would be preferable, as it would create more certainty for
workers.
Commissioner Christine Wil
son dissented from the FTC’s proposed rule. Commissioner Wilso
n argued
that non-compete clauses are an inappropriate subject for rulemaking because their competitive effects are
highly fact-specific and depend on the business justification for particular clauses.
Congressional Research Service
3
Commissioner Wilson also criticized the Commission for initiating a rulemaking on a subject with which
it h
ad little enforcement experience, relying on academic literature containing
mixed conclusions, and
discounting the procompetitive business justifications of non-compete clauses.
Finally, Commissioner Wilson questioned the FTC’s legal authority to adopt the proposed rule. She
predicted that such a rule would be successfully challenged on the grounds that (1) the FTC has
no
authority to engage in UMC rulemaking, (2) th
e major questions doctrine precludes the FTC from
adopting a non-compete ban without clear congressional authorization, and (3) Section 5 of the FTC Act
represents
an impermissible delegation of legislative authority if construed to authorize a non-compete
ban. These legal arguments are discussed further below.
Legal Issues
Does the FTC Have Substantive UMC Rulemaking Authority?
As discussed, the FTC has grounded its assertion of UMC rulemaking power i
n Sections 5 and 6(g) of the
FTC Act. The provisions contain broad language: Section 5 prohibits “unfair methods of competition,”
while Section 6(g) empowers the FTC to issue rules “for the purpose of carrying out” the FTC Act.
There is case law supporting the FTC’s claim of rulemaking authority. In its 1973 decision in
National
Petroleum Refiners Association v. FTC, the D.C. Circuit held that Section 6(g) authorizes the FTC to
promulgate substantive Section 5 rules defining “unfair or deceptive acts or practices” (UDAP) and
UMC.
Two years later, Congress responded to
National Petroleum Refiners in t
he Magnuson-Moss Act, which
established special procedures for the FTC’s UDAP rulemakings under a
new Section 18 of the FTC Act.
Magnuson-Moss did not, however, purport to alter the FTC’s UMC rulemaking authority. Th
e statute
contains a provision disclaiming an intent to “affect any authority of the Commission to prescribe rules
(including interpretive rules), and general statements of policy, with respect to unfair methods of
competition in or affecting commerce.”
While Magnuson-Moss did not by its terms affect the FTC’s UMC rulemaking authority, the Commission
has not made extensive use of that power. The FTC has promulgated one substantive antitrust rule—a
1968 regulation (preceding Magnuson-Moss) that involved price discrimination in the men’s clothing
industry, which the agency never enforced an
d later repealed.
Some commentators have argued that the absence of a robust historical pedigree for UMC rules—along
with several principles of statutory construction—suggest that the FTC does not have substantive UMC
rulemaking authority. Among other things, they contend that the D.C. Circuit’s decision in
National
Petroleum Refiners gave short shrift to certai
n canons of interpretation that may have greater purchase
with modern courts; that th
e structure of the FTC Act suggests Section 6(g) confers ministerial rather than
substantive rulemaking authority; and that t
he major questions doctrine precludes the FTC from issuing
rules involving issues of
“vast economic and political significance” without
“clear congressional
authorization.”
Proponents of UMC rulemaking hav
e responded that the text of Section 6(g) does not identify any
limitations on the rulemaking power it confers and that the major questions doctrine is primarily relevant
to th
e scope of the FTC’s rulemaking authority, rather than the threshold question of whether Section 6(g)
allows the agency to promulgate substantive rules.
A separate Legal Sidebar provides a more detailed discussion of these issues.
Congressional Research Service
4
Would the FTC’s Non-Compete Proposal Exceed the Scope of the
Commission’s UMC Rulemaking Authority?
Som
e commentators hav
e argued that the FTC’s non-compete proposal would—if implemented as a final
rule—exceed the scope of the Commission’s UMC rulemaking authority, even if the agency has the
authority to promulgate other types of UMC rules. The remainder of this Sidebar addresses two issues
raised by such arguments: (1) the breadth of Section 5 of the FTC Act in relation to t
he Sherman Antitrust
Act, and (2) th
e major questions doctrine.
Section 5 of the FTC Act and the Sherman Act
Under current law, non-competes can be challenged under state law or the Sherman Act, though the latter
is generally not an attractive vehicle for such lawsuits for the reasons discussed below.
State laws governing non-competes
vary. A few states categorically ban non-competes, some prohibit
them for specific categories of employees, and others subject them to reasonableness review.
Under the Sherman Act, by contrast, challenges to non-compete clauses ar
e evaluated using a standard
called t
he Rule of Reason, which requires plaintiffs to show that the defendant possesses market power
and that the specific conduct at issue harmed competition. Under this test, lawsuits targeting non-compete
clauses are
seldom successful. In some cases, for example, courts hav
e rejected antitrust challenges to
non-compete clauses because plaintiffs failed to allege that the clauses had market-wide anticompetitive
effects, as opposed to negative effects on the individuals bound by the clauses.
Accordingly, a key question in assessing the FTC’s authority to ban non-compete clauses is the extent to
which Section 5 of the FTC Act extends beyond the Sherman Act’s prohibitions. Whil
e courts have
recognized that Section 5 is
broader than the Sherman Act, the precise scope of its extra coverage—often
called the FTC’s “standalone” Section 5 authority—is unsettled.
As discussed, the FTC’s proposal offers multiple theories in support of its preliminary conclusion that
non-compete clauses represent a UMC under Section 5.
One theory involves th
e contention that non-compete clauses constitute “restrictive conduct that
negatively affects competitive conditions.” The Commission argues that non-compete clauses have such
effects
“in the aggregate,” noting that the effect of individual clauses may be “marginal” or “impossible to
discern statistically.” The rule would thus not require proof of competitive harm in individual cases, nor
would it demand proof of specific indicia of harm (
e.g., proof that an employer has labor market power).
Additionally, the rule would not allow employers to justify particular clauses with evidence of
procompetitive benefits.
It remains to be seen whether courts would be receptive to this type of potential paradigm shift in antitrust
enforcement. While the history of antitrust is filled wit
h examples of bright-line rules—and some types of
conduct remai
n per se illegal today—the consistent trend has been towar
d flexible standards that require
courts to evaluate the details of specific challenged conduct.
In Sherman Act cases, modern courts have tended to conclude that
per se illegality is appropriate
“only
after considerable experience” evaluating a specific practice. The FTC does not have such experience
challenging or regulating non-compete clauses. The limited Section 5 case law involving such clauses
also endorses a fact-specific approach. In a 1963 decision, the Seventh Circuit
rejected the FTC’s
allegation that a business-to-business non-compete clause violated Section 5. In doing so, the court
explained that non-compete clauses “are legal unless they are unreasonable as to time or geographic
scope” and declined to conclude that such clauses represent
per se Section 5 violations. The FTC’s
authority to implement a categorical prohibition of non-competes may thus depend on the extent to which
Congressional Research Service
5
its Section 5 rulemaking authority reaches beyond the standards that govern judicial recognition of new
per se offenses.
The FTC’s second theory justifying its conclusion that non-competes represent a UMC—that such clauses
are “exploitative and coercive” as applied to non-senior-executive workers—may raise similar issues. In
elaborating on this theory, the FTC distinguished between exploitation and coerci
on at the time an
employment contract is signed and exploitation and coerci
on at the time of a worker’s potential departure
from an employer.
Non-compete clauses are “exploitative and coercive” at the time of contracting, the FTC argues, because
they take advantage of
unequal bargaining power between employers and workers. Such clauses are
“exploitative and coercive” at a worker’s prospective departure, the agency claims
, because they “force a
worker to either stay in a job they want to leave or choose an alternative that likely impacts their
livelihood.”
It is unclear how a court would evaluate these arguments. In its analysis of Section 5, the FTC references
decisions from the 1960s affirming the FTC’s findings of Section 5 violations where defendants used
economic power in one market to harm competition in another market. Another decision the Commission
cites involved a marketing scheme that
exploited the inability of children to protect themselves. Whether
the concepts of “exploitation” and “coercion” employed in these cases would be sufficient to support a
broad non-compete ban remains uncertain.
The FTC’s distinction between exploitation and coercion
at the time of contracting and exploitation and
coercion
when a worker seeks to leave a job may also be a point of contention. The FTC frames these as
“independent” theories of unfairness, suggesting that the agency has preliminarily concluded that
non-compete clauses may be “exploitative and coercive” when a worker seeks to leave a job even if they
are not “exploitative and coercive” when workers agree to them.
That claim may raise issues that are broadly similar to those that arise in connection wit
h antitrust
aftermarkets—markets for goods used together with a durable product, but where the goods are purchased
after consumers have purchased the durable product (
e.g., printer ink, razor blades). These types of goods
have generat
ed questions regarding the circumstances in which a firm that lacks market power in a
primary equipment market can nevertheless harm competition in a related aftermarket. While the
Supreme Court has
held that such harm is possibl
e, recent case law has taken a
narrow approach in
applying the doctrine—especially when aftermarket terms are clearly set forth in
a primary market
contract. In those circumstances, courts have reasoned, consumers can incorporate aftermarket restrictions
into their decisions in the competitive primary market.
If a court applied similar reasoning to the FTC’s theories regarding non-compete clauses, it may be
skeptical of the claim that such clauses can be “exploitative and coercive” when a worker seeks to leave a
job if they are not “exploitative and coercive” at the time of contracting. In that case, the FTC’s theory
that non-competes are “exploitative and coercive” at the time of contracting would be the linchpin of its
exploitation-and-coercion arguments.
To support that theory, the FTC’s proposal appeals to inequalities in bargaining power between employers
and workers. In particular, the Commissi
on contends that most workers depend on income from their jobs
to meet basic needs; that employers “generally” have “considerable” market power based on factors like
concentrated labor markets and job search costs; and that outsourcing and declines in union membership
have further eroded the negotiating positions of workers. The FTC al
so argues that workers face
inequalities in bargaining power when negotiating employment terms because employers are repeat
players in such negotiations, workers typically do not seek the assistance of counsel in reviewing
employment contracts, and workers likely exhibit cognitive biases that interfere with their ability to
appropriately evaluate employment terms.
Congressional Research Service
6
These arguments implicate some of the issues discussed above. Even if a court was to credit the FTC’s
empirical claims about the level of competition and bargaining inequality in many labor markets, a rule
that applies to all labor markets without admitting any affirmative defenses may invite judicial
skepticism, based on the trends that have characterized modern antitrust.
While the FTC’s proposed rule thus stands in some tension with aspects of prevailing antitrust doctrine,
another principle may support the agency’s efforts:
Chevron deference. When
Chevron applies, courts
defer to an agency’s reasonable interpretation of an ambiguous statute that the agency is charged with
administering. Some commentators hav
e argued that the FTC would be eligible for
Chevron deference
when promulgating UMC rules. Others, however, hav
e noted that the Supreme Court has qualified the
availability of
Chevron deference in several recent decisions, including decisions involving t
he major
questions doctrine.
The Major Questions Doctrine
As noted, the Supreme Court has relied on the major questions doctrine to reject claims of regulatory
authority involving issues of
“vast economic and political significance” when an agency has been unable
to establish
“clear congressional authorization” for the relevant power.
As discussed i
n this Sidebar, the Court recently applied this doctrine i
n West Virginia v. EPA, holding that
the Environmental Protection Agency exceeded its authority under Section 111(d) of the Clean Air Act by
promulgating emission guidelines for power plants that were based in part on shifting electric energy
generation from higher-emitting sources to lower-emitting ones.
It is possible a reviewing court would conclude that a non-compete clause ban implicates “major
questions” and thus requires explicit congressional authorization. Given th
e prevalence of non-compete
clauses, a ban may have a significant economic impact. The FTC’s proposal estimates that
roughly 30
million workers are subject to a non-compete clause and that the proposed rule would increase workers’
earnings by
$250 billion to $296 billion a year. The proposed rule would also arguably have significant
political impact—for example, by preempting
state laws that currently govern non-competes. In one
recent case, the Supreme Court
justified its application of the major questions doctrine in part based on
the fact that a federal regulation implicated the landlord-tenant relationship and thereby “intrude[d] into
an area that is the particular domain of state law.” Because non-compete clauses have traditionally been
regulated primarily at the state level, similar reasoning might support the application of the major
questions doctrine to a non-compete ban.
If a court determined that a non-compete ban implicated “major questions,” the FTC would need to
establish clear congressional authorization for such a rule, which may be a difficult task in light of the
potential ambiguities involving Section 5’s scope.
For its part, the FTC has denied that its authority is uncertain. Three Commissioners hav
e contended that
the FTC’s proposal is grounded in “clear statutory authority” to identify and address UMC.
Considerations for Congress
The FTC’s authority to prohibit non-compete clauses is primarily an issue of statutory interpretation.
Congress could thus attempt to clarify the agency’s authority via statute.
Congress could also regulate non-competes directly. In the 117th Congress, the Workforce Mobility Act
(S. 483 and H.R. 1367) would have prohibited non-competes, subject to exceptions for the sale of a
business or the dissolution of a partnershi
p. S. 2375, the Freedom to Compete Act, would have adopted a
narrower approach and banned non-competes for certain low-wage workers.
Congressional Research Service
7
Deregulatory action is also possible. Congress could, for example, enact preemptive legislation
authorizing non-compete clauses that meet certain conditions.
Author Information
Chris D. Linebaugh
Jay B. Sykes
Legislative Attorney
Legislative Attorney
Disclaimer
This document was prepared by the Congressional Research Service (CRS). CRS serves as nonpartisan shared staff
to congressional committees and Members of Congress. It operates solely at the behest of and under the direction of
Congress. Information in a CRS Report should not be relied upon for purposes other than public understanding of
information that has been provided by CRS to Members of Congress in connection with CRS’s institutional role.
CRS Reports, as a work of the United States Government, are not subject to copyright protection in the United
States. Any CRS Report may be reproduced and distributed in its entirety without permission from CRS. However,
as a CRS Report may include copyrighted images or material from a third party, you may need to obtain the
permission of the copyright holder if you wish to copy or otherwise use copyrighted material.
LSB10905 · VERSION 1 · NEW